Painless Devaluation, Scrap Metal Boom
The BLS reported December U.S. Import/Export prices yesterday. The numbers showed that a weaker dollar has not made U.S. exports a lot cheaper, or foreign imports a lot more expensive. They also show that it’s good time to be short-term bullish on oil, long-term bullish agricultural commodities, and ready to tear out the plumbing of the vacant tract homes in the nearest neighborhood when interest rates rise….But first…the numbers. Export prices rose 0.2% in December, after a half a percent rise in November. And over the last twelve months, export prices are actually up 2.2%. That’s the biggest one-year gain since 1995. But when you look closer, higher export prices don’t mean that U.S. businesses were suddenly more competitive because of a weaker dollar. In fact, one-way of looking at the marginally higher export prices is that it inflation in commodity prices, pure and simple. Prices for feed, wheat, and soybeans were up 13.6% in the last twelve months. By contrast, non-agricultural prices were up only 1.3% in the last year. Where is the profit windfall for U.S. exporters? On the export side of the ledger, prices for non-agricultural industrial goods and metals are rising, up 5.9% for the year on the strength of oil. Capital goods prices have fallen half a percent in the last twelve months, while consumer goods prices have actually increased 0.8%. The textbook theory is that higher export prices mean a weaker dollar is working its soothing powers on exporters. Exporters are able to raise prices without raising costs in the local currency. Yet even on a year-over-year basis, the BLS numbers show that the only real growth in export prices (and presumably in profits) is in commodities, not manufactured goods. On the import side of the ledger, the textbook theory is that a weaker dollar raises the price of foreign goods. Nice theory. But does it hold up? Import prices ARE up in the last twelve months, by 1.9%. But again, it was energy and commodity prices driving the growth--and price increases in those kinds of products do not cause consumers to choose a domestic over a foreign producer. It does not make U.S. firms any more profitable. Petroleum prices were the single largest factor in the rise in any event, up 9.1% in the last twelve months. Non-petroleum import prices--prices for everything else--are up ony 1% in the last year. And prices for imported capital goods were actually down 0.2%. So, the dollar can have can be competitively weak, yet it does not cause a substantial increase in the price of foreign goods. And by extension, there is NO windfall for U.S companies. By the way, where import prices WERE rising, they were rising for imports of metal, industrial supplies, and materials (up 6.7% over twelve months). Again, this just confirms that while price inflation may not be showing up in finished goods, it IS showing up in raw materials, i.e. commodities. Why has the theory that a weaker dollar will lead to higher exports and lower imports broken down? A weaker dollar should, repeat should, cause import prices to go up. To compensate for the falling dollar, foreigners raise the prices of their goods to retain profit margins. But that hasn’t happened at all. And that’s one part of the explanation. Import prices haven’t risen much because foreign producers pay such cheap labor and manufacturing costs, they can afford even a smaller profit margin and don’t have to raise prices. What’s more, in Asia at least, the dollar’s fall has been matched by competitive devaluations, keeping Asian profit margins on exports to the U.S. relatively stable. That’s not to say the dollar’s weakness hasn’t caused any pain for some foreign producers. Import prices rose on goods from Europe and Latin America. EU import prices are up 3.3% in the last twelve months. Latin American import prices are up 3.5%. But the price indexes for Japan and the newly industrialized countries in Asia show that import prices actually decreased by 0.4% over the last twelve months. Greenspan (who, based on his recent speech, believes in a free market for everything EXCEPT interest rates) seems to have concluded that all of this is just fine. It’s a painless devaluation. While the dollar’s decline hasn’t had any discernable benefits to U.S. exports, it hasn’t really had any discernable costs either. Since there hasn’t been any rise in consumer price inflation, or in finished goods, Greenspan can look the other way, keep his foot on the monetary gas pedal by keeping rates low, and hope for a more robust recovery. But there HAS been some inflation…namely in crude oil prices and commodities. And here, indirectly, we may finally find an event that forces the Fed to raise rates. Two, even. First, dollar weakness IS putting a big hurt on foreign holdings of U.S. financial assets. When the currency loss on dollar-denominated financial assets becomes prohibitive to owning them, either the Fed will raise rates to strengthen the dollar, OR, foreign holders will cut their losses and get out (or at least reduce acquisitions of dollar-denominated assets.) THAT, as patient readers know, has not happened yet. Keep in mind, though, that the weak dollar is not the only factor to consider here. Stock markets themselves will have a lot to say about the willingness of foreigners to bear the currency pain. Even if the dollar stabilizes at around 1.25 to the euro….stock markets will still have to deliver big gains to continually offset the currency cost of owning the dollar. A month or two of poor stock market performance brings the pain home to Europe even more acutely, and could itself account for the selling of U.S stocks and bonds--with our without more belly flopping by the dollar. But the more indirect cause of higher U.S. interest rates and a move to boost the dollar may come from higher oil prices. Oil, at least in euro terms, as NOT risen that much at all. I refer to a chart produced by my main macro man, Greg Weldon, showing that euro strength has kept crude prices from appreciating in euro terms.

0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home